Advertisement

We need your help now

Support from readers like you keeps The Journal open.

You are visiting us because we have something you value. Independent, unbiased news that tells the truth. Advertising revenue goes some way to support our mission, but this year it has not been enough.

If you've seen value in our reporting, please contribute what you can, so we can continue to produce accurate and meaningful journalism. For everyone who needs it.

bahri altay via Shutterstock
VOICES

Opinion Voter turnout isn’t a problem, so let’s stop all the hand-wringing

Do we really need to solve the ‘problem’ of low turnout?

WE’RE ALL WORRIED about the decline in turnout, aren’t we? Politicians, academics and other worthies march up to Glenties every year to worry about our failing politics, and to self-flagellate about our failure to reform our failing politics.

And it’s not just us we’re worried about this year. With the results of the 2014 European elections we worry that other parts of Europe have gone bad. They’ve elected nationalists! Let’s forget that the vote for the racist nationalists, who I assume are the ones we don’t like, has gone down in many countries. Something must be done!

The standard analysis is that the Front National in France and Britain’s UKIP were elected because so many good people didn’t bother to vote. It’s probably true that low turnout led to an inflated sense of support for anti-EU parties. It is also likely that in general elections in these countries, more people vote.

But do we really need to solve the ‘problem’ of low turnout?

Why do people not vote? 

First of all, the decision not to vote might be an expression of dissatisfaction with the government or the political system. A Fine Gael voter might abstain from voting in Dún Laoighaire in order to send a message to the government. He’ll vote for them again in the general election; he’s making a point.

Another voter might wish to abstain because she’s tired of politics and does not wish to engage in public affairs through conventional electoral politics.

If this is a problem it is a problem that there isn’t an adequate choice for voters in the political spectrum, or perhaps that those that do offer alternative voices are hopelessly divided. It is associated with the fact that many see conventional electoral politics as irrelevant – if even ‘democratic revolutions’ don’t change much, why bother vote?

The symptom of this problem is that people are disengaged from conventional politics. Turnout is just one indicator of that disengagement.

Compulsory voting 

In the Irish Times David Farrell suggests confronting turnout head on. He makes a number of suggestions, such as introducing an electoral commission and making it easier to register to vote. These would be useful additions to our democratic architecture, but they are irrelevant to our evaluation of conventional politics.

Farrell makes an even more radical suggestion – introduce compulsory voting.

Compulsory voting works. Many more people vote in countries that force their citizens to turn out to vote than in those that don’t.

There are of obvious ideological objections. We should not be forced to do anything. In a free society it should be our choice whether to vote or not.

A less powerful objection might be that we will force people who are ignorant of public issues to vote, thus giving them a voice that isn’t as considered as those who would choose to vote regardless.

Turnout is not the problem

While the first objection should kill the idea of compulsory voting stone dead, we can disregard Farrell’s suggestion for another reason: Turnout is not the problem. It’s not even the symptom of the problem. It’s just an indicator of the problem. Turnout allows us to measure disengagement, but forcing people to vote isn’t going to make them more engaged.

When we try to manipulate indicators directly we are committing a grave sin in public policy. In the 1970s Charles Goodhart coined (the modestly titled) Goodhart’s Law – when a measure becomes a target is ceases to be a good measure.

Policymakers are too often ignorant of Goodhart’s insight. We mix up indicators of policy problems with the problems themselves and try to tackle the indicator head on. It was for this reason that introducing targets for waiting times in A&E failed in the UK. Hospital administrators told to reduce the waiting time to see clinical staff reacted by inventing the post of ‘Hello nurse’. These nurses only role was to greet new arrivals so they could claim for their statistics that the patient had been seen even though no clinical examination of treatment occurred. There was no clinical improvement, but waiting times tumbled.

It was this confusion of the indicator and the cause of a problem that led a minister for education to suggest that every child in the country be sent five books. The minister was reacting to research that indicated that children in houses with at least five books in them performed much better on reading tests. Happily, the flaws in the minister’s logic were pointed out.

The conversations in Glenties aren’t wholly pointless; there is much wrong with our political system, and we should be open to introspection about our failings and willing to adapt. But we should start with understanding the problems. These relate to the capacity of our State to continue to deliver the improvements to people’s lives we saw in much of the second half of the 20th century. Then we can stop the endless hand-wringing about irrelevancies.

Dr Eoin O’Malley is senior lecturer in politics at the School of Law and Government, Dublin City University.

Read: Fianna Fáil selects candidate to run for Dáil seat in Roscommon/South Leitrim by-election

Your Voice
Readers Comments
30
    Submit a report
    Please help us understand how this comment violates our community guidelines.
    Thank you for the feedback
    Your feedback has been sent to our team for review.